The euro was not created for purely economic reasons. If it is deemed a worthwhile project for political reasons, and is viewed as mutually beneficial to all participants, the eurozone could be made a viable venture – though certain minimal structural conditions must be met.
FRANKFURT – Europe’s monetary union is screeching toward the abyss, unintentionally, but apparently inexorably. Greece will most likely not meet the criteria to receive further financial assistance from its eurozone partners and the International Monetary Fund. Europeans will then need to decide whether to let Greece go. The exit option would not improve Greece’s chances of successful adjustment, and it would come at a steep price for the eurozone: it would be “in the money” – and priced accordingly.
A Greek exit could, one hopes, be managed. The European Central Bank would contain the collateral damage by flooding Europe’s banking system with liquidity (against subpar collateral). Or it will reluctantly re-launch its purchases of public-sector debt in secondary markets, capping the other peripheral eurozone economies’ interest-rate spreads relative to the core.
Thus, dire circumstances would once again force the ECB’s hand. As the strongest European institution, it is systematically vulnerable to being taken hostage, compelled to underwrite a further lease on life for the euro. In this light, ECB President Mario Draghi’s recent vow to do “whatever it takes” to save the euro came as no surprise.
Back in 1999, it seemed that Jacques Rueff, an adviser to Charles de Gaulle, had been vindicated: L’Europe se fera par la monnaie. Eleven European countries chose to give up their national currencies (or, more technically, the nominal exchange rate).
These countries understood “one money” as a quasi-physical corollary of “one market.” Independent national monetary policies in a common market were rightly seen as infeasible, given Europeans’ preference for stable exchange rates and open financial markets. This called for a single currency – and thus shared responsibility for monetary policy.
Today, however, we may need to re-phrase Rueff’s axiom: Et l’Europe se défait par les marchés financiers, unless, that is, Europe comes up with a viable institutional design.
Access every new PS commentary, our entire On Point suite of subscriber-exclusive content – including Longer Reads, Insider Interviews, Big Picture/Big Question, and Say More – and the full PS archive.
Subscribe Now
Given the euro’s current travails, it is instructive to recall arguments stressed in the run-up to monetary union. As the Nobel laureate economist Robert Mundell and others spelled out in the 1960’s, relinquishing nominal exchange rates emphasizes three alternative mechanisms to cushion regional adjustment: inter-regional fiscal transfers, intra-union migration, and, most importantly, labor markets capable of adapting to shocks.
Unfortunately, these mechanisms were anathema at the time. Conveying the message that nothing would have to change appeared to be far more attractive.Thus, Mundellian arguments were not heeded when the euro’s institutional blueprint was conceived. Indeed, the Stability and Growth Pact, like Europe’s no-bail out clause, ignored the pertinent economic theory (some say any economic theory). Regional current-account balances were interpreted as the upshot of infallible optimizing behavior by market participants, rather than, for example, the result of a real-estate bubble in Spain and elsewhere.
Only after the fact, since the fall of 2009, has it become conventional wisdom that those intra-union current-account deficits, accumulating over a decade, were untenable. Now, given monetary union, the adjustment must be carried out by changing domestic prices relative to tradable goods – that is, by engineering a depreciation of the real exchange rate.
In view of the quite substantial overvaluation in some periphery countries, this will be a time-consuming process. (Germany needed almost a decade to adapt to a smaller property bubble in its new eastern Länder in the early 1990’s.) But it is difficult to imagine that market participants will have the required patience. That is why supporting the euro requires forceful and credible crisis containment – whatever it takes.
But the ongoing crisis also highlights a second design flaw, unacknowledged in Mundell’s argument: the challenges arising from integrated financial markets (including those for the credibility of the no-bail out clause). Under normal circumstances, unimpeded cross-border capital flows come with all of the advertised benefits in terms of better resource allocation and higher productivity. In the wake of the crisis, however, given the shared fate of national governments and banks, a significant home-bias re-emerged. Ring-fencing became national supervisors’ default option, and monetary conditions became re-segmented along national lines.
This translates into a significant disparity in financial institutions’ funding costs. The immediate upshot is a substantial divergence in firms’ cost of funds, with many small and medium-size enterprises even losing access to credit completely. As a result, capital expenditure – already a fragile proposition, given weak demand – has plummeted, triggering a vicious circle of shrinking GDP, lower tax revenues, higher expenditures, and further destabilization of public-debt positions.
The problem is not only that such heterogeneity in funding conditions renders a common monetary policy difficult to conduct. More important, given that some regions now face interest-rate spreads that are the functional equivalent of having their own currencies (without a central bank), some eurozone members might at some point wonder why they should not formalize what is de facto a reality. Market participants already do, to a degree.
None of this is inevitable. The euro was not created for purely economic reasons. If it is deemed a worthwhile project, and is viewed as mutually beneficial to all participants, the eurozone could be made viable. In order to achieve this, certain minimum conditions must be met. In addition to flexible labor markets, a viable eurozone presupposes a (minimal) fiscal insurance mechanism. And it calls for not only common financial regulation, but also for eurozone-wide supervision of financial institutions, including common deposit insurance and a shared bank-resolution scheme.
This is a tall order. And it will take time to implement. But the immediate short-run alternative – letting Greece (and potentially others) fall by the wayside – would carry a substantial price. Periphery countries would be forced to pay a significant premium to compensate investors for assuming a redenomination (partial default) risk. And, with that, the eurozone would become as vulnerable as any fixed exchange-rate system has historically proven to be.
To have unlimited access to our content including in-depth commentaries, book reviews, exclusive interviews, PS OnPoint and PS The Big Picture, please subscribe
A promising way to mobilize more climate finance for developing countries is to expand the use of “solidarity levies”: global levies on carbon dioxide emissions and other economic activities that channel proceeds to developing countries. The benefits of scaling up such measures would be far-reaching.
Although Americans – and the world – have been spared the kind of agonizing uncertainty that followed the 2020 election, a different kind of uncertainty has set in. While few doubt that Donald Trump's comeback will have far-reaching implications, most observers are only beginning to come to grips with what those could be.
consider what the outcome of the 2024 US presidential election will mean for America and the world.
FRANKFURT – Europe’s monetary union is screeching toward the abyss, unintentionally, but apparently inexorably. Greece will most likely not meet the criteria to receive further financial assistance from its eurozone partners and the International Monetary Fund. Europeans will then need to decide whether to let Greece go. The exit option would not improve Greece’s chances of successful adjustment, and it would come at a steep price for the eurozone: it would be “in the money” – and priced accordingly.
A Greek exit could, one hopes, be managed. The European Central Bank would contain the collateral damage by flooding Europe’s banking system with liquidity (against subpar collateral). Or it will reluctantly re-launch its purchases of public-sector debt in secondary markets, capping the other peripheral eurozone economies’ interest-rate spreads relative to the core.
Thus, dire circumstances would once again force the ECB’s hand. As the strongest European institution, it is systematically vulnerable to being taken hostage, compelled to underwrite a further lease on life for the euro. In this light, ECB President Mario Draghi’s recent vow to do “whatever it takes” to save the euro came as no surprise.
Back in 1999, it seemed that Jacques Rueff, an adviser to Charles de Gaulle, had been vindicated: L’Europe se fera par la monnaie. Eleven European countries chose to give up their national currencies (or, more technically, the nominal exchange rate).
These countries understood “one money” as a quasi-physical corollary of “one market.” Independent national monetary policies in a common market were rightly seen as infeasible, given Europeans’ preference for stable exchange rates and open financial markets. This called for a single currency – and thus shared responsibility for monetary policy.
Today, however, we may need to re-phrase Rueff’s axiom: Et l’Europe se défait par les marchés financiers, unless, that is, Europe comes up with a viable institutional design.
Introductory Offer: Save 30% on PS Digital
Access every new PS commentary, our entire On Point suite of subscriber-exclusive content – including Longer Reads, Insider Interviews, Big Picture/Big Question, and Say More – and the full PS archive.
Subscribe Now
Given the euro’s current travails, it is instructive to recall arguments stressed in the run-up to monetary union. As the Nobel laureate economist Robert Mundell and others spelled out in the 1960’s, relinquishing nominal exchange rates emphasizes three alternative mechanisms to cushion regional adjustment: inter-regional fiscal transfers, intra-union migration, and, most importantly, labor markets capable of adapting to shocks.
Unfortunately, these mechanisms were anathema at the time. Conveying the message that nothing would have to change appeared to be far more attractive.Thus, Mundellian arguments were not heeded when the euro’s institutional blueprint was conceived. Indeed, the Stability and Growth Pact, like Europe’s no-bail out clause, ignored the pertinent economic theory (some say any economic theory). Regional current-account balances were interpreted as the upshot of infallible optimizing behavior by market participants, rather than, for example, the result of a real-estate bubble in Spain and elsewhere.
Only after the fact, since the fall of 2009, has it become conventional wisdom that those intra-union current-account deficits, accumulating over a decade, were untenable. Now, given monetary union, the adjustment must be carried out by changing domestic prices relative to tradable goods – that is, by engineering a depreciation of the real exchange rate.
In view of the quite substantial overvaluation in some periphery countries, this will be a time-consuming process. (Germany needed almost a decade to adapt to a smaller property bubble in its new eastern Länder in the early 1990’s.) But it is difficult to imagine that market participants will have the required patience. That is why supporting the euro requires forceful and credible crisis containment – whatever it takes.
But the ongoing crisis also highlights a second design flaw, unacknowledged in Mundell’s argument: the challenges arising from integrated financial markets (including those for the credibility of the no-bail out clause). Under normal circumstances, unimpeded cross-border capital flows come with all of the advertised benefits in terms of better resource allocation and higher productivity. In the wake of the crisis, however, given the shared fate of national governments and banks, a significant home-bias re-emerged. Ring-fencing became national supervisors’ default option, and monetary conditions became re-segmented along national lines.
This translates into a significant disparity in financial institutions’ funding costs. The immediate upshot is a substantial divergence in firms’ cost of funds, with many small and medium-size enterprises even losing access to credit completely. As a result, capital expenditure – already a fragile proposition, given weak demand – has plummeted, triggering a vicious circle of shrinking GDP, lower tax revenues, higher expenditures, and further destabilization of public-debt positions.
The problem is not only that such heterogeneity in funding conditions renders a common monetary policy difficult to conduct. More important, given that some regions now face interest-rate spreads that are the functional equivalent of having their own currencies (without a central bank), some eurozone members might at some point wonder why they should not formalize what is de facto a reality. Market participants already do, to a degree.
None of this is inevitable. The euro was not created for purely economic reasons. If it is deemed a worthwhile project, and is viewed as mutually beneficial to all participants, the eurozone could be made viable. In order to achieve this, certain minimum conditions must be met. In addition to flexible labor markets, a viable eurozone presupposes a (minimal) fiscal insurance mechanism. And it calls for not only common financial regulation, but also for eurozone-wide supervision of financial institutions, including common deposit insurance and a shared bank-resolution scheme.
This is a tall order. And it will take time to implement. But the immediate short-run alternative – letting Greece (and potentially others) fall by the wayside – would carry a substantial price. Periphery countries would be forced to pay a significant premium to compensate investors for assuming a redenomination (partial default) risk. And, with that, the eurozone would become as vulnerable as any fixed exchange-rate system has historically proven to be.